Marketplace May 2016
Tim Congdon
Two kinds of nation are found in the
modern world—a minority (28) that
belong to the European Union and a
majority (more than 160) that do not. Most
of the world’s roughly 190 nations have their
own currencies. All have assets that constitute
national wealth, and a great many have
stock exchanges where the assets can be
bought and sold.
Economists and others have put forward
numerous theories to explain the valuation
of both currencies and assets, where the
word “assets” embraces houses, land, equities,
bonds and so on. Currency markets behave
crazily from time to time, but the most
plausible view is that an exchange rate is just
another price. Like every price it is set by
supply and demand. If governments and central
bankers create too much money relative
to demand (as they did in Germany in 1923
and Zimbabwe in 2008, and as they are doing
now in Venezuela), the value of money falls.
No theory proposes that the value of a
currency depends on the nation’s loneliness,
its geographical location or its abstention
from this or that international organisation.
Counter-examples are so obvious that they
can be limited to one paragraph. Switzerland
is a country of eight million people, little
more than 1 per cent of the continent (defined
mostly widely) in which it is situated. It
does not belong to the EU and until 2002 it
did not belong to the United Nations. The
Swiss franc is about as lonely a currency as
could be imagined. But it has appreciated
against all the world’s other currencies, including
the euro, in the last 50 years. Japan
could claim to be Asia’s most peripheral nation,
in the atlas sense. But, again, its currency
has been impressively strong for much
of the last four decades.
Further, not one school of macroeconomic
thought has argued that assets within
EU member states have systematically more
expensive valuations than nations which
are not EU member states. No evidence
whatsoever has been presented that companies
quoted on the stock markets of Germany
and France are more highly rated (in
terms of price/earnings ratios, market-value-to-book
ratios and so on) than their
equivalents on the stock markets of the US
or Australia, or that any such superiority in
valuation is attributable to their EU membership.
Not a single published academic paper
has attempted to claim that EU membership
by itself improves the valuation
criteria of corporate equity.
Yet the promoters of Project Fear and far
too many headline writers have been busy in
the last few weeks with silly alarmism. They
say that the day after a vote for Brexit will
see collapses in the value of the pound and
the stock market. Can they not see that
Brexit would merely result in the UK becoming
just like any other non-EU nation?
No facts or data show that EU membership
affects the long-run valuation basis of the
currencies, stock markets and assets in general
of EU member states relative to the currencies,
stock markets and assets of non-EU
member states. The sky hasn’t fallen in because
the US, Japan, Canada and others are
not EU members; the sky will not fall in because
the UK is not an EU member.
Remember that the UK has had a dress
rehearsal for the day after Brexit. In the
summer of 1992 its economy was suffering
from a severe recession clearly due to its
membership of the European exchange rate
mechanism. A number of observers—including
a weirdly-named “Liverpool Six” group
of economists (of whom I was one)— said that
the Exchange Rate Mechanism, with its
fixed exchange rate between the pound and
other European currencies, was responsible
for too-high interest rates. The UK therefore
needed to leave, so that monetary policy
could again be geared to our own needs.
But the then Prime Minister, John Major,
disagreed. According to his memoirs, “We
had looked at the precipice and decided
against jumping.” In the event, the UK did
not jump over the precipice, or leap in the
dark, or plunge into the abyss, or otherwise
throw itself downwards into some great unknown.
Instead, it was pushed. Overwhelming
selling pressures in the foreign exchange
markets forced the pound out of the ERM on
“Black Wednesday”.
Except that it turned out not to be black
at all. Although the pound did indeed fall in
late 1992, interest rates came down and the
economy recovered. The period to the May
1997 general election saw steady output
growth with moderate inflation. Black
Wednesday became Golden Wednesday.
The pound’s value against other currencies
was higher when Major lost the general election
than when he and his Cabinet colleagues
had behaved so idiotically on Black/
Golden Wednesday almost five years earlier.
When politicians use words like “precipice”
and “abyss” in matters of economic policy,
they are waffling. Even more than usual,
they don’t know what they are talking about.
http://www.timcongdon4ukip.com/docs/2016_Standpoint_May_Non_EU_EU_countries.pdf